Advertisement

How to recover lost revenue from big global firms that legally avoid taxes

Tuesday April 23 2019
J1

Activists of Campact and of the Network for Tax Equity dressed as te CEOs of big corporations -- BASF, Amazon, Apple -- protest in front of the Finance Ministry in Berlin, Germany on May 24, 2018. PHOTO | EMMANUELE CONTINI

By JAYATI GHOSH

For some time now, multinational companies have been gaming the rules of the global economy to minimise their tax liability —or even eliminate it altogether.

And for some time now, the Independent Commission for the Reform of International Corporate Taxation (ICRICT) has argued for the unitary taxation of multinationals.

Fortunately, there have been some encouraging signs that the idea of a unitary tax is gaining traction.

Introducing a global minimum effective corporate-tax rate of between 20 per cent and 25 per cent on multinationals, as the Reform of International Corporate Taxation (of which I am a member) advocates, would greatly weaken these firms’ financial incentives to use transfer pricing among their subsidiaries to shift profits to low-tax countries. Moreover, a global minimum would end the race to the bottom in which countries lower their national tax rates in order to attract multinational companies.

These global tax revenues could then be allocated among governments based on factors such as the company’s sales, employment and number of digital users in each country — rather than on where multinationals decide to locate their operations and intellectual property.

Although tax experts and policymakers initially dismissed the ICRICT’s proposal as impractical, even former naysayers now recognise the validity of this approach.

Advertisement

LOST REVENUE

Most important, it is now widely acknowledged that taxing multinational firms based on “where value is created” encourages massive — and legal — tax avoidance through “base erosion and profit shifting,” whereby companies take advantage of loopholes and differences in tax rules to move profits to low- or no-tax jurisdictions.

The resulting revenue losses for governments are mind-boggling. The International Monetary Fund has estimated that countries under the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development may be losing $400 billion in tax revenue each year because of profit shifting, with non-OECD countries losing a further $200 billion.

As the United Nations’ 2019 Financing for Sustainable Development Report points out, tax avoidance hits developing countries particularly hard, because their governments tend to rely on corporate tax revenues, and because companies’ declared profits are more sensitive to tax rates than in developed countries.

Multinationals’ tax-avoidance strategies can also distort cross-border trade statistics. Global firms increasingly report intra-company trade and investment in intangible assets such as intellectual property, primarily for tax-arbitrage purposes. This creates “ghost trade flows” that have little or no connection with real economic activity.

This legal tax avoidance is most evident in digital companies, mainly because digitalisation makes it hard to establish where production takes place. As a consequence, a digital multinational’s revenues typically bear no relation to its reported profits and resulting tax bill.

Amazon, for example, has paid no federal tax in the US for the past two years. In 2018, the company generated more than $232 billion in worldwide revenue, but reported profits of only $9.4 billion, on which it could then claim various deductions and offsetting credits. And in 2017, Google legally moved nearly $23 billion to Bermuda through a shell company based in the Netherlands, dramatically reducing its foreign tax bill.

Governments are finally trying to claw back this lost revenue.

In January, the OECD proposed standardised rules for taxing digital companies across its member countries, building on measures already proposed in the European Union.

The OECD proposals go beyond the “arm’s-length principle,” which seeks to compel multinationals to bring transfer pricing into conformity with some market-value basis. They also go beyond current rules that limit taxation authority to countries where a multinational has a physical presence.

This initiative is welcome, and not only because it could help to reduce tax competition among developing countries. For too long, multinationals — and digital firms in particular — have used existing tax rules to avoid paying taxes in countries where their products are consumed.

BENEFIT

At the moment, the various proposals to address this (from the US, the UK, and the G24 group of developing countries) all envisage expanding these “market” countries’ authority to tax global firms.

The UK proposal is the narrowest in this regard, while the G24’s is the broadest.

But developing countries also want any global corporate-tax system to recognise their increasing importance as producers for traditional multinationals. Digital companies may be the largest and most prominent tax avoiders, but a tax reform that focused only on these firms would clearly not be in developing countries’ interests.

The US government is also against changing tax rules only for (mostly American) digital companies, because it would mean the US giving taxation authority to other countries and receiving nothing in return.

The geographic allocation of multinationals’ global profits and tax payments therefore needs to reflect supply-and-demand factors. This would take into account both sales (revenues) and employees (as a proxy for production).

Such a system would benefit developing and developed countries alike.

The arguments in favour of such an approach are overwhelming. But multinationals of both the digital and traditional sort remain politically powerful. Even – or especially – in the digital economy, old-fashioned lobbying still counts.

Jayati Ghosh is a professor of economics at Jawaharlal Nehru University in New Delhi, executive secretary of the International Development Economics Association, and a member of the Independent Commission for the Reform of International Corporate Taxation.

Advertisement